Last week Michael Lind asked a silly question (“The question libertarians just can’t answer”): if libertarianism is so great, why hasn’t any country tried it?
The question is silly because the libertarian answer is obvious: Libertarianism is great for ordinary people, but not for the power elites that control countries and determine what policies they implement, and who don’t welcome seeing their privileged status subjected to free-market competition. And ordinary people don’t agitate for libertarian policies because most of them are not familiar with the full case for libertarianism’s benefits, in large part because the education system is controlled by the aforementioned elites.
Lind’s question is analogous to ones that might have been asked a few centuries ago: If religious toleration, or equality for women, or the abolition of slavery are so great, why haven’t any countries tried them? All such questions amount to asking: If liberation from oppression is so great for the oppressed, why haven’t their oppressors embraced it?
Now E. J. Dionne proposes a different answer (“Libertarianism’s Achilles’ Heel”) to Lind’s question: “We had something close to a small government libertarian utopia in the late 19th century and we decided it didn’t work.”
Leaving aside the Orwellian use of “we” – as a serious claim about history, this is absurd. Even if we ignore, as we shouldn’t, the anti-libertarian legal disabilities imposed on women, nonwhites, and homosexuals (i.e, the majority of the population), it remains true that the late 19th century American economy was characterized by vigorous and systematic government intervention on behalf of big business (wrapped sometimes in laissez-faire rhetoric and sometimes in progressive rhetoric). A government that routinely brings in police or the army to break up strikes is hardly a laissez-faire regime.
In the 1880s, free-market anarchist Benjamin Tucker identified the domination of business interests in the Gilded Age as grounded in a variety of state-imposed monopolies, stressing four in particular: Protectionist tariffs; the monopolization of credit through government control of the money supply; the suppression of competition via informational monopolies (patents and copyrights); and the assignment of titles to land and natural resources on the basis of expropriation and political pull rather than homesteading and trade. Alongside these, Tucker listed the monopolization of security services represented by the institution of the state itself.
The rigging of the market in favor of big business did not end with the Gilded Age. Dionne’s claim that in that era “monopolies were formed too easily” ignores historical research by James Weinstein and Gabriel Kolko showing that the supposedly anti-business regulations of the Progressive era (and likewise, Butler Shaffer has shown, those of the New Deal) were actually lobbied for by the corporate elite, in order to prop up monopolies that could not survive in an unhampered market. Dionne’s vision of the New Deal as coming to the rescue of a government that was previously “helpless” and “handcuffed” by “anti-government ideology” is ludicrous; Roosevelt’s big-government, pro-cartelization policies were largely a continuation of Hoover’s. And given the destruction of affordable health insurance in the early 20th century via the political might of the medical establishment, as documented by historian David Beito, Dionne’s claim that laissez-faire left the poor “unable to afford health insurance” is literally adding insult to injury.
The myth of 19th-century laissez-faire is useful to statists on both the left and the right. As contemporary market anarchist Kevin Carson observes, “advocates of the regulatory-welfare state must pretend that the injustices of the capitalist economy result from the unbridled market, rather than from state intervention in the market,” since otherwise “they could not justify their own power as a remedy.” And by the same token, “apologists of big business” need to “pretend that the regulatory-welfare state was something forced on them by anti-business ideologues, rather than something they themselves played a central role in creating.”
Dionne’s identification of the Tea Party as representing “anti-statist libertarianism” shows that he has let himself be bamboozled by the anti-government rhetoric of what is mainly (with some honorable exceptions) a pro-big-government campaign for crony capitalism, intrusive morals legislation, harassment of peaceful immigrants, and a sanguinary foreign policy. The regulations against which Tea Partiers rail are mainly secondary regulations, the belt over the bones, designed merely to ameliorate the effects of those primary regulations that maintain the essential power structures in place.
A better question we might ask Lind and Dionne: if the intrusive state is so great, why does it need to retain its clients by force, rather than letting them peacefully opt out?
This is the state of mainstream American right and left politics. IMO this flows in the MSM because it is criticism of the actions of the system, but does not question the nature of the system itself. The debate ties commercials together. I don't consider myself an anarchist; however, I do find value in the questions that anarchists raise. IMO we are a long way from finding the right answers to these questions, but it's important that we start asking them more often. Otherwise, we aren't going to find a soft landing post-Capitalism.The myth of 19th-century laissez-faire is useful to statists on both the left and the right. As contemporary market anarchist Kevin Carson observes, “advocates of the regulatory-welfare state must pretend that the injustices of the capitalist economy result from the unbridled market, rather than from state intervention in the market,” since otherwise “they could not justify their own power as a remedy.” And by the same token, “apologists of big business” need to “pretend that the regulatory-welfare state was something forced on them by anti-business ideologues, rather than something they themselves played a central role in creating.”